Skip to main content

Climate Policy Info Hub Home Link

Main menu

  • Issues & Sectors
  • About

Climate Policy Info Hub

Scientific Knowledge for Decision-Makers

Role of Countries in Climate Negotiations

  • Generate PDF
PDF

Issues: 

  • International Climate Policy

Sectors: 

  • Energy

Keywords: 

  • climate alliances
  • implementation
  • interaction
  • interest group
  • negotiations
  • NGOs
  • participation
  • policies
  • post 2020
  • scenarios
  • stakeholders
  • targets
twitter share facebook share linkedin share
twitter share facebook share linkedin share
Role of Countries in Climate Negotiations
Since the 1990s, almost all countries in the world negotiate on international climate policies as Parties to the UN Framework Convention on Climate Change (UNFCCC). This has resulted in several milestones, but it has also become clear that countries are diverse and have different negotiation interests, which complicates reaching agreements. This knowledge package maps and explains the interaction of the Parties during UNFCCC negotiations.

1. How countries negotiate: sovereign states and like-minded groups

Since the early 1990s, international climate policy negotiations have taken place within the context of the UN Framework Convention on Climate Change (UNFCCC), with participation of almost all countries in the world. As Parties to the UNFCCC, countries act as sovereign states and in the tradition of decision-making by consensus generally all votes count. However, climate negotiations have also shown that it is often difficult to reach agreement among countries.

There are several reasons for that1. First, countries are economically, socially and environmentally diverse. Their financial capacity to respond to climate change impacts or to act on mitigation differs as well as the degree to which countries feel responsible for climate change. Second, countries may play 'negotiation games' in an attempt to arrive at a more favorable negotiation outcome for them, possibly at the expense of others. Third, climate negotiations have long been hampered by lack of scientific insights on global warming and whether and how people influence climate systems. As a result, rather than negotiations being guided by a clear problem statement and goals, formulating climate goals has long been a topic of negotiations itself.

According to the UN tradition2, Parties, while they are each represented by national delegations, are grouped according to their regions, mainly for administrative reasons:

  • African States,
  • Asian States,
  • Eastern European States,
  • Latin American and the Caribbean States, and
  • Western European and Other States (e.g., including EU, Australia, Norway, Switzerland and USA).

In order to have their substantive interests better presented at negotiations, Parties usually organise themselves in 'like-minded' groups. The main groups are:

  • Group of 77 (G-77), which was founded in 1964 and has nowadays over 130 developing country members; China generally collaborates with G-77 so that the group's inputs to the COP are usually tabled as G-77&China submissions,
  • Alliance of Small Island States (AOSIS), which is a coalition of 43 low-lying and small island countries (which are mostly also member of the G77&China group),
  • Least Developed Countries (LDC), which contains 50 countries and which share a common interest in, e.g., vulnerability and adaptation to climate change,
  • European Union (EU), which as a regional economic integration organisation has become a Party to the UNFCCC itself,
  • Umbrella Group, which is a loose coalition of non-EU developed countries, and
  • Environmental Integrity Group (EIG), which comprises Mexico, Liechtenstein, Monaco, the Republic of Korea and Switzerland.

In addition, there are several other groups, such as OPEC (Organisation of Petroleum Exporting Countries), CACAM (Central Asia, Caucasus and Moldova), BASIC (Brazil, South Africa, India and China), and COMIFAC (Central African Forestry Commission).

2. What determines the negotiation positions of countries as UNFCCC Parties?

Ideally, negotiations are supported by a clear identification and description of the (environmental) problem to be addressed with corresponding goals3. This helps countries assess whether and to what extent the course of a negotiation process is in line with the upfront goal(s). Countries then agree on forming an international coalition to implement a pathway towards the goal(s) and with clear descriptions of each country’s responsibility in the negotiated package1.

However, such an ideal situation has been difficult to realise in climate negotiations. Early projections by the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change (IPCC)4 indicated how climate change and corresponding climatic impacts may occur due to increasing GHG emissions, but these scenarios were surrounded by several uncertainties. Only since the Cancun Agreements of 2010, there has been a clearly formulated longer term political goal, based on science, of limiting global average temperature increases to 2°C5.

A second reason why climate policy negotiations have deviated from an ‘ideal’ negotiation pathway is related to game-theoretical aspects. Investing in GHG emission reductions may well require economic restructuring with accompanying socio-economic costs and addressing questions such as: what would such a restructuring look like, how to balance short-term socio-economic costs with possible longer-term benefits,6 how would it affect a country’s competitiveness and whose further interests are negatively or positively affected7?

Most countries will generate different answers to these questions due to their different short-, medium- to longer-term development priorities, welfare levels, and perception of the urgency of the climate change issue. Moreover, countries may be reluctant to agree on GHG emission reductions8:

  1. If it feels that it could benefit from measures taken by other countries, instead of investing in climate actions itself (free rider behavior).
  2. If it feels that its actions are not or insufficiently met with comparable actions by other countries.

3. Polarised Positions Impede Commitment

These climate negotiation characteristics and polarised positions of the negotiating parties have complicated the introduction of legally binding commitments with strong enforcement mechanisms for all countries. For instance, although the Kyoto Protocol contained legally binding quantified commitments, these were only formulated for developed country Parties, of which the USA refused to ratify the protocol (in 2001) and Canada refused to comply with its commitments (in 2011). Moreover, as the Protocol did not set out mitigation commitments for any developing countries, it did not address the growing emissions of rapidly industrialising developing countries. 

Within the context of negotiations on the Durban Platform (2011), some developing countries have expressed the view that no nation should be fully exempted from climate mitigation responsibilities. Thus the hitherto solid block of G77 developing countries has increasingly split up into smaller groups, which has also softened the usual strict distinction between developed and developing country Parties. Also the positions of developed countries have evolved. Source (see Figure 1a and b). Over time, the Umbrella Group divided into separate positions. In addition, while the EU is in principle a single player (negotiation Party), the positions of EU Member States are not unanimous.

As a result, some negotiation groups now include both developed and developing countries. An example of that is the Environmental Integrity Group, which emerged in 2001, and which includes developed and developing countries that have agreed to undertake ambitious mitigation policies.

One possible implication of this development towards a softer distinction between developed and (rapidly growing) developing countries can be that negotiations can focus more strongly on limiting or reducing GHG emissions of major emitting countries, including a number of developing countries. Nevertheless, despite these developments, developing countries continue to underline at negotiations9 the importance, in their view, of the UNFCCC principle of common but differentiated responsibilities10.

The evolution of positions and country groupings since the start of the negotiations is visualized in the six images of Figure 1.

The evolution of positions and country groupings since the start of the negotiations
The process from before 2001 until  2009 and beyond

The evolution of positions and country groupings since the start of the negotiations | The process from before 2001 until  2009 and beyond | Figure 1: Evolution of climate negotiation groupings over time: from major differentiated blocks to a more common global responsibility | Source: Michaelowa A., Castro P., Bagchi C. (2013), D2.1: Report on Stakeholder Mapping: Multi-level interaction of climate policy stakeholders in the run-up to the 2015 agreement, POLIMP, Climate Strategies and University of Zurich

Figure 1: Evolution of climate negotiation groupings over time: from major differentiated blocks to a more common global responsibility
Source: Michaelowa A., Castro P., Bagchi C. (2013), D2.1: Report on Stakeholder Mapping: Multi-level interaction of climate policy stakeholders in the run-up to the 2015 agreement, POLIMP, Climate Strategies and University of Zurich

4. Fragmentation as Progress

After the failure to reach a global agreement at the Copenhagen UNFCCC Conference of the Parties (COP 15) in 2009, the fragmentation of positions increased (see Figure 1c). While this may seem cause for concern, this fragmentation can in fact be attributed to actual progress in the negotiations, as well as to the increasing number of issues under discussion, such as finance, inclusion or exclusion of sectors, the definition of developing countries’ responsibilities, etc. As negotiations become more complex, the fragmentation of positions does not therefore necessarily reflect a lack of commitment by the participants.

The Paris COP in 2015 (COP 21) is expected to introduce a number of commitments with flexible approaches to accommodate the rising diversity. Despite divergent internal interpretations of the CBDR principle, or of the importance of adaptation, the G77 group will still remain influential. If it manages to reach a common compromise position on the CBDR principle, this could indeed help in reaching a substantial agreement between the parties at the COP.

Sources
  • 1. a. b. Gaast, W.P. van der Gaast, 2015. International Climate Negotiation Conditions: Past and Future, PhD thesis at University of Groningen, the Netherlands.
  • 2. UNFCCC, 2014c. Party Groupings. [Online] Available at: http://unfccc.int/parties_and_observers/parties/negotiating_groups/items...)
  • 3. see, a.o., Fells, 2012, pp. 57-58, Susskind, et al., 2000, and APRAISE, 2012.
  • 4. Houghton., J., Jenkins, G. & Ephraums, J., 1990. Climate Change: The IPCC Scientific Assessment (1990). Cambridge, Great Britain, New York, NY, USA and Melbourne, Australia : Cambridge University Press; IPCC, 1995. Second Assessment Report: Climate Change - Summary for Policy Makers, Geneve, Switzerland: Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change.
  • 5. Above pre-industrial times levels. UNFCCC, 2011. Decision 1/CP.16- The Cancun Agreements: Outcome of the work of the Ad Hoc Working Group on Long-term Cooperative Action under the Convention, para. 4, page 2, http://unfccc.int/resource/docs/2010/cop16/eng/07a01.pdf#page=2
  • 6. As the EU Climate Policy Roadmap for 2050 has shown, longer-term economic benefits of an economic restructuring towards a low-emission or even 85% carbon-free society could even be positive due to lower energy cost, stimulating of renewable energy technology producing and service sectors, etc.
  • 7. Jackson, T., 2009. Prosperity Without Growth: Economics for a Finite Planet. 1st ed. London: Earthscan; Gaast, W. v. d. & Begg, K., 2012. Challenges and Solutions for Climate Change. London, UK: Springer.
  • 8. Tulkens, H., 1998. Co-operation versus Free-Riding in International Environmental Affairs: Two Approaches. In: Game theory and the environment. Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar, pp. 30-44
  • 9. UNFCCC, 2014. Decision -/CP.20 Lima call for climate action, [ available at: http://unfccc.int/files/meetings/lima_dec_2014/application/pdf/auv_cop20...
  • 10. UNFCCC, 1992a, United Framework Convention on Climate Change, page 2.
Related Knowledge Package(s) 
Observer NGOs and the International Climate Negotiations
Authors 
Monica Alessi
Wytze van der Gaast
Editor 
Matthias Duwe
Knowledge Package Citation 
Monica Alessi and W.P. van der Gaast (2016): "Role of Countries in Climate Negotiations". CLimate PolicyInfo Hub,12 July 2016. Online available at: http://climatepolicyinfohub.eu/role-countries-climate-negotiations
  • Log in to post comments
  • PDF

Issues & Sectors

The Climate Policy Info Hub has been created within the POLIMP project which has received funding from the European Union's Seventh Framework Programme for Research, Technological Development and Demonstration under Grant Agreement Number 603847.

POLIMP Project Logo

Legal Notice • Privacy Notice • Glossary