Skip to main content

Climate Policy Info Hub Home Link

Main menu

  • Issues & Sectors
  • About

Climate Policy Info Hub

Scientific Knowledge for Decision-Makers

Market-Based Climate Policy Instruments

  • Generate PDF
PDF

Issues: 

  • EU Climate Policy
  • Emission Trading

Sectors: 

  • Energy

Keywords: 

  • cost and benefits
  • economic costs
  • effectiveness
  • emissions
  • emissions trading
  • global climate
  • incentives
  • policies
  • policy instruments
  • policy-mix
  • taxes
  • technology
twitter share facebook share linkedin share
twitter share facebook share linkedin share
Market-Based Climate Policy Instruments
European climate policies apply a mix of different policy instruments to impose emissions reductions. Main instrument categories include non-market-based and market-based instruments. This knowledge package introduces the workings of market-based instruments currently part of the EU’s climate policy toolbox.

Within the European Union (EU) there is a mix of climate policies in place. These instruments can be grouped into two different types: non-market based and market-based instruments. The following article explains market based instruments in place in the EU, based on a categorisation produced under the research project CECILIA20501. The policy types are illustrated with examples. As a large part of the theory is based on economic theory this article sometimes borrows language and terms from this field. Information on non-market-based instruments can be found in the article "Non-market-based climate policy instruments in the EU". A discussion of both concepts is available in the article "Discussion of climate policy instrument types applied in the EU".

1. Market-based-instruments

Market-based instruments are indirect regulatory instruments, which influence actors' behaviour by changing their economic incentive structure. Costs from environmental externalities, such as greenhouse gas (GHG) emissions, are usually not reflected in consumption or investment decisions but are nonetheless imposed on third parties. Therefore, these types of policies work by reflecting the environmental impact of a certain action by attaching a cost to it, to signal and provide an incentive to the polluter to reduce this impact.

Figure 1 shows the breadth of market-based instruments used in the EU. The most important instrument types here are environmental taxes and emissions trading.

Taxonomy of Climate Policy Instruments
Environmental policy instruments divided into market-based and non-market-based instruments

Taxonomy of Climate Policy Instruments | Environmental policy instruments divided into market-based and non-market-based instruments | Figure 1: Taxonomy of climate policy instruments | Source: Görlach, B. (2013)

Figure 1: Taxonomy of climate policy instruments
Source: Görlach, Benjamin, “What constitutes an optimal climate policy mix? Defining the concept of optimality, including political and legal framework conditions”, CECILIA2050 Deliverable 1.1, (Berlin: Ecologic Institute, February 2013), online available at: http://cecilia2050.eu/system/files/G%C3%B6rlach%20%282013%29_What%20cons...

2. Taxes: getting the price right is essential

The idea of environmental taxation was first introduced by Arthur Cecil Pigou, which is why these taxes are sometimes also referred to as Pigouvian taxes. Environmental taxes add directly to the price of a certain good or service, which ideally should reflect the environmental externalities caused by production and/or consumption of this good or service. The rise in costs is usually passed through to the end consumer. In theory, the consumer reacts with a reduction of demand, as the price increases. However, consumer reactions are hard to predict and depend on availability of substitutes and perceptibility of the price signal. As a tax fixes a price and thereby indirectly influences behaviour, it is therefore also crucial to set the price at the right level. For these reasons environmental taxes bear a certain degree of uncertainty regarding their environmental effectiveness.

Furthermore, environmental taxes change the relative values of input factors in the economy. When energy prices rise, this means that relatively labour becomes cheaper. If revenues are additionally spent on tax reductions in other areas, such as labour, this effect even multiplies. The tax therefore has the potential to produce a so called "double dividend", i.e. tackling environmental problems and reduce taxation in other areas. However, it is a fundamental characteristic of an effective environmental tax that its tax base will erode. Moreover, environmental taxes tend to have negative distributional effects, since lower income households are generally more affected and might also be more limited in the substitution options available to them2.

The most relevant environmental taxes in the EU are excise duties on energy products (used for stationary purposes and for transport) and vehicle taxation.

3. Taxes: Tricky to use as a common EU policy due to consensus requirements

The main drawback to use taxes as a climate policy instrument on the European level is the need for consensus between Member States regarding their introduction, as well as the detailed policy design e.g. tax rates and tax bases. As this consensus is very hard to achieve, environmental taxation so far has proven to be a policy instrument with low practical feasibility at the European level.  

The EU determines minimum tax rates for energy products used for heating, as a fuel or as electricity in the Energy Taxation Directive3. However, many Member States apply exemptions or reductions. Moreover, these minimum tax rates are not based on the carbon content of the fuels but mainly on weight or volume4. However, some Member States apply an explicit carbon tax on top of the regular energy excise duties. In 2012, energy taxes accounted for 75% of environmental tax revenues in the EU5.

Vehicle taxes include registration taxes, ownership taxes and road use charges in form of vignettes or distance-based toll systems. In 2012, transport taxes accounted for 21% of environmental tax revenues in the EU5.

4. Emissions Trading  

Cap and trade systems, like taxes, generate economic incentives to change the behaviour of societal actors and reduce pollution. But instead of introducing a fixed price which is added on the price of a certain good or service, the starting point in a cap and trade system is a limit on the physical emission quantity (cap) of a harmful substance, introduced by a regulatory authority, which issues emission allowances according to the maximum limit it has defined. This is either done by grandfathering (free allocation according to certain criteria, such as past pollution) or auctioning, which generates revenue for the governments. The emission allowances can be traded on a market and polluters can buy and sell them according to their needs, with the allowance price determined by supply and demand. Polluters carry out mitigation actions until it is cheaper to buy an allowance on the market than to mitigate a further emission unit. As a result, those polluters with the cheapest mitigation options will reduce the most. This theoretically guarantees the most cost-effective mitigation pathway for society2.

Cap and trade systems are in theory more dependable than taxes since emissions are capped. However, in real applications market design can become very complex. Furthermore, the demand for allowances also depends on the economic situation. In a recession economic activity will decrease and thereby emissions, which will drive down allowance prices. The low allowance price will not serve as an incentive to invest in low carbon technologies and which can create a lock-in effect, as no further action is required to achieve the emission cap. This can make future emission reductions more expensive, threatening the theoretical cost-effectiveness of an emissions trading system (ETS).

The EU Emissions Trading System (EU ETS) is an example for an implemented cap and trade system. It was first introduced in 2005 and revised in 20096. It covers all heavy energy-using installations in power generation and manufacturing industry within the EU Member States, Norway, Iceland and Liechtenstein, as well as aviation. The EU ETS covers around 45% of greenhouse gas emissions in the EU7. The EU ETS target is a reduction of 21% of emissions compared to 2005 levels until 2020 and 80-90% until 2050 compared to 1990. The EU ETS is the first and largest emissions trading system in the world8.

5. Removal of perverse incentives

This instrument refers to the removal of subsidies for environmentally harmful activities and products, such as subsidies for the extraction or production of fossil fuels, exemptions from energy taxes, or fossil fuel subsidies to keep the price level low. Furthermore, this also includes the removal of further incentives rewarding harmful activities, such as the abolition of liability exemptions1.

Regarding the extent of these so called perverse incentives, the environmental impact of their abolishment can be potentially large, as the following example shows: In 2012, total support provided by EU Member States to coal power generation (hard coal and lignite) summed up to some EUR 10 billion (not including historic support), improving the profitability of the investment, mainly in the form of investment grants, exemptions from fuel taxes and support to decommissioning and waste disposal. Meanwhile total external costs of coal power generation are estimated at EUR 86 billion9.

6. Others

Furthermore, there are liability instruments which "impel concerned parties to internalize external costs through the threat of consequential costs"1. Deposit refund systems charge consumers an upfront payment for improper waste disposal. The refund is a reward for returning the waste to the right collection point.

Sources
  • 1. a. b. c. Görlach, Benjamin, “What constitutes an optimal climate policy mix? Defining the concept of optimality, including political and legal framework conditions”, CECILIA2050 Deliverable 1.1, (Berlin: Ecologic Institute, February 2013), online available at: http://cecilia2050.eu/system/files/G%C3%B6rlach%20%282013%29_What%20cons....
  • 2. a. b. Michael Common and Sigrid Stagl, Ecological Economics. An Introduction. (Cambridge University Press, 2009).
  • 3. Council Directive 2003/96/EC of 27 October 2003 restructuring the Community framework for the taxation of energy products and electricity. OJ L 283 of 31.10.2003.
  • 4. European Commission, “Smarter energy taxation for the EU: proposal for a revision of the Energy Taxation Directive”, Communication from the Commission to the European Parliament, the Council and the European Economic and Social Committee. COM(2011) 168/3.
  • 5. a. b. Eurostat, “Environmental tax revenues”. Website section, online available at: http://appsso.eurostat.ec.europa.eu/nui/submitViewTableAction.do (last accessed on 27 August 2014).
  • 6. Directive 2009/29/EC of the European Parliament and of the Council of 23 April 2009 amending Directive 2003/87/EC so as to improve and extend the greenhouse gas emission allowance trading scheme of the Community. OJ L 140, 5.6.2009, p. 63–87; Directive 2008/101/EC of the European Parliament and of the Council of 19 November 2008 amending Directive 2003/87/EC so as to include aviation activities in the scheme for greenhouse gas emission allowance trading within the Community, OJ L 8, 13.1.2009, p. 3–21; Directive 2004/101/EC of the European Parliament and of the Council of 27 October 2004 amending Directive 2003/87/EC establishing a scheme for greenhouse gas emission allowance trading within the Community, in respect of the Kyoto Protocol's project mechanisms. OJ L 338, 13.11.2004, p. 18–23; Directive 2003/87/EC of the European Parliament and of the Council of 13 October 2003 establishing a scheme for greenhouse gas emission allowance trading within the Community and amending Council Directive 96/61/EC. OJ L 275, 25.10.2003.
  • 7. Ms Hedegaard, Answer to Parliamentary Question E-012616/2013. Online available at: http://www.europarl.europa.eu/sides/getAllAnswers.do?reference=E-2013-01... (last accessed on 23 June 2014).
  • 8. Jon Birger Skjærseth and Jørgen Wettestad, “The EU Emissions Trading System Revised (Directive 2009/29/EC)” in The New Climate Policies of the European Union, eds. Sebastian Oberthür and Marc Pallemaerts (Brussels: s University Press, 2010).
  • 9. Alberici, Sacha, Sil Boeve, Pieter van Breevoort, Yvonne Deng, Sonja Förster, Ann Gardiner, Valentijn van Gastel, Katharina Grave, Heleen Groenenberg, David de Jager, Erik Klaassen, Willemijn Pouwels, Matthew Smith, Erika de Visser, Thomas Winkel, Karlien Wouters Ecofys, “Subsidies and costs of EU energy – Final report” (Ecofys, November 2014), online available at: https://ec.europa.eu/energy/sites/ener/files/documents/ECOFYS%202014%20S....
Related Knowledge Package(s) 
Non-Market-Based Climate Policy Instruments
European Climate Policy - History and State of Play
Progress towards the 2020 Greenhouse Gas Target in Europe
International Ambition on Targets for the Post-2020 Era
Overview of Climate Targets in Europe
The EU Emissions Trading System: an Introduction
Discussion of Climate Policy Instrument Types Applied in the EU
Further Readings 
  • CECILIA 2050. Optimal EU Climate Policy. http://cecilia2050.eu/.
  • Common, M. and Stagl, S. (2009). Ecological Economics. An Introduction. Chapter 11: Environmental policy instruments. Cambridge University Press.
  • Grubb, Michael, Jean-Charles Hourcade, Karsten Neuhoff, Planetary Economics – Energy climate change and the three domains of sustainable development, (Abingdon: Routledge, 2014). 
  • OECD (2013): Taxing Energy Use. A graphical analysis. OECD Publishing.
  • Skoerseth, J. and Wettestad, J. (2010). The EU Emissions Trading System Revised (Directive 2009/29/EC). In Oberthür, S. and Pallemaerts, M. (Eds.). (2010) The New Climate Policies of the European Union. Brussels University Press. Pp. 65-91.
Authors 
Andreas Prahl
Elena Hofmann
Editor 
Matthias Duwe
Knowledge Package Citation 
Andreas Prahl, Elena Hofmann (2016): "Market-Based Climate Policy Instruments". Climate Policy Info Hub, 27 June 2016. Online available at: http://climatepolicyinfohub.eu/market-based-climate-policy-instruments
  • Log in to post comments
  • PDF

Issues & Sectors

The Climate Policy Info Hub has been created within the POLIMP project which has received funding from the European Union's Seventh Framework Programme for Research, Technological Development and Demonstration under Grant Agreement Number 603847.

POLIMP Project Logo

Legal Notice • Privacy Notice • Glossary